Sunday, 26 December 2010
Alex Ross on Bob Dylan
Joan Didion said that Joan Baez was a personality before she was a person and the same could be said of Dylan.
Tuesday, 30 November 2010
John Steinbeck on the decline of the USA
"Americans, over invested in material toys and saddled with debt are bored, anguished and discontented and no longer capable of the heroism which rescued them from the terrifying poverty of the Great Depression. And underneath it all, building energies like gases in a corpse. When that explodes, I tremble to think what will be the result." John Steinbeck to his editor Pascal Covici, 1960.
Buiter on MCM
From Buiter’s Sovereign Debt Crisis Update
Portugal and Greece:
After an Irish agreement with the EU/IMF, the market’s attention is likely to turn to Portugal’s sovereign, which at current levels of interest rates and growth rates, is less dramatically, but quietly, insolvent, in our view. We consider it likely that it will need to access the EFSF soon.
Greece is de facto insolvent, in our view, all the more so after the recent debt and deficit revisions. As long as Greece remains sufficiently compliant with the conditionality of its EU/IMF program, sovereign debt restructuring is likely to be postponed at least until mid-2013, when its EU/IMF programme expires. At that point, it likely will be transferred to the EFSF or its successor. Whether its debt will be restructured at that stage, including haircuts, will depend on factors beyond the sustainability of its debt.
Spain:
For now, the markets have put Spain in Italy’s sovereign risk class when, in our view, it should be closer to Portugal and Ireland once its banking sector problems are recognised. We argued before that the EFSF should be much larger (€2trn). Should Spain need assistance, it will stretch the resources of the EFSF, perhaps beyond its current limits. There may be some room to expand the size of the EFSF. But, in our view, once Spain needs assistance, the support of the ECB will be critical (by purchasing Spanish sovereign debt through its Securities Markets Program — SMP — and funding Spanish banks using Spanish sovereign debt or sovereign-guaranteed financial instruments as collateral or by making loans to or purchasing the debt of the EFSF, legally a limited liability company that could even be made an eligible counterparty of the Eurosystem for this purpose).
In the longer term, there may be a need for large-scale restructuring of the debt of the Spanish banking sector and possibly the sovereign. At longer horizons, high debt levels and political instability in Italy and Belgium may yet give rise to fundamentally warranted sovereign debt crises, while self-justifying crises are possible even in the near term, despite roughly balanced structural primary budgets.
And if you thought that the EU/IMF bailout marked the end of Ireland’s troubles, think again says Buiter:
Accessing external sources of funds will not mark the end of Ireland’s troubles. The reason is that, in our view, the consolidated Irish sovereign and Irish domestic financial system is de facto insolvent. The Irish sovereign cannot from its own resources ‘bail out’ the banks and make its own creditors whole. In addition, a fully-fledged bailout (permanent fiscal transfer) from EA partners or the ECB is most unlikely. Therefore, either the unsecured non-guaranteed creditors of the banks, and/or the creditors of the sovereign may eventually have to accept a restructuring with an NPV haircut, even if it is not a condition for accessing the EFSF or the EFSM at present.
FT Alphaville on the Merkel Crash Mechanism
Posted by Izabella Kaminska on Nov 30 11:15.
It was first highlighted by economist Paul de Grauwe.
But, dare we say, the so-called ‘Merkel crash’ is quickly becoming analyst consensus for what really triggered this latest European debt rout.
As BNP Paribas points out on Tuesday:
Yesterday did see EMU spreads widening further despite the release of a credible Irish rescue package. The reason for continued peripheral selling pressure may be related to the funding needs of banks as highlighted in the stability report of the BoP. It was last Tuesday when Germany showed a blueprint for the further regulation of the private bond market. Germany aims introducing this law in 2011 and would like to harmonise this law EU wide. The blue print suggested that next to creditors and debtors it would be the regulator to decide if and when there would be hair cuts or maturity lengthening on outstanding bonds announced. Hence, last Tuesday set the starting point for bank CDS’s moving sharply up as markets assumed that bonds which such kind of clause (regulator deciding) would be difficult to sell. Spanish banks will have come to the capital market in the first half of 2011 and will have to issue more bonds than the Spanish sovereign. The stability report of the BoP highlighting this problematic will keep investors concerned and the EUR offered.
And thus the European Stability Mechanism is transforms ever more officially into the European Instability Mechanism (EIM), alternatively to be known as Merkel’s Crash Mechanism (MCM).
Vorsprung durch mechanismen.
Saturday, 20 November 2010
Michael Dirda on John Banville
William Easterly on Foreign Aid for Scoundrels in the NYRB
...The concept of development helps rationalize the position of autocrats by postulating an unstoppable transition toward a bright future. This is why donors call all poor countries “developing.” Once the donors started paying lip service to democracy, they could label undemocratic aid recipients as “democratizing.” Let’s call this the Gerund Defense for supporting dictators....
...The Gerund Defense has the attraction of being irrefutable. We don’t know the future, so we don’t know whether a particular event is a “setback” to “building institutions,” or whether the “building” is a myth. We could of course observe the actual trend in “democratizing”—but this has been discouraging in Ethiopia, where parties and politicians that seriously challenge the government risk prison. Donors could conceivably overlook anything, even the 1994 Rwanda genocide, as a temporary “setback” to an “innate tendency.” Such a view is not as easily dismissed as you might think.
Giles Harvey on Saint Bob in the NYRB
.....Dylan has certainly made some astonishing records since then (1966), most notably The Basement Tapes, John Wesley Harding, and Blood on the Tracks (1975); but for years at a stretch—from 1971 to 1975, from 1978 to 1989—he went into creative tailspin, releasing album after album of generally insipid material......as the years went by, Dylan found himself trapped inside the aspic of his own legend.
Tuesday, 16 November 2010
Roubini on Eurozone sovereign debt restructuring mechanisms
Since most likely an exchange offer under threat of default is considered—as it is by rating agencies that considered them as coercive thus triggering a selective default rating–as a credit event that triggers the CDS an holder of CDS protection would be paid regardless of whether he/she has underlying exposure to the bonds and regardless of whether he/she tries to sabotage the debt restructuring. In effect, the holder of CDS protection has no incentive to sabotage a restructuring because such a restructuring is by itself a credit event that triggers the CDS regardless of whether the restructuring is successful or not.........
In summary, a European SDRM is not necessary to achieve an orderly restructuring of public debts of eurozone members. Such restructuring can be achieved in an orderly manner any time via the traditional tool of exchange offers that have been successfully been used for emerging market sovereigns in distress. Thus, the current debate on a European SDRM is a total red herring: The reason why the EU has so far decided to provide financing to member states in distress is not the lack of a legal mechanism for an orderly restructuring; rather, it reflects concern about systemic contagion. But an orderly restructuring via exchange offers can significantly reduce such a risk while providing significant debt servicing relief to sovereign that are financially distressed via an orderly—if coercive—debt restructuring.
The current tragedy is that the European debate on a crisis resolution mechanism or SDRM has had perverse effects: .... the talk about a European SDRM has been the trigger of the recent blow-out of Irish spreads and created greater turmoil than order. Additionally, the confusing and contradictory remarks of EU officials and national leaders on when the restructuring mechanism will take effect and to which debts it will apply (new or old ones) has created greater uncertainty among investors. The reality is that, regardless of what the EU says or doesn‘t say, the probability of a coercive restructuring of the Greek or Irish debt is totally independent of whether a European SDRM will be created in 2013 or later and whether its terms would apply to new or old debt. The EU has zero effective power in deciding—via a new legal mechanism—whether Greece or any other EZ sovereign will restructure its debt and when.
Indeed, if Greece does not regain market access it will be forced to restructure its debts when the IMF/EU bailout program expires even if, as possible, the IMF or the EU were to decide to maintain its exposure to Greece upon expiration of that official support. In effect, if Greece doesn‘t regain its market access, its need to finance its new yearly deficits and to rollover private claims coming to maturity will force a debt restructuring. To prevent this, IMF/EU would have to not only extend their existing program but, on top of that, significantly increase its lending/financial commitments beyond the current €110 billion lending envelope since Greece will have large financing needs beyond 2012 given its ongoing fiscal deficit and need to rollover private claims coming to maturity.
This is why the recent statement by some European finance ministers asserting that the proposed debt restructuring mechanism will apply only to debts issued only after 2013—a statement which backpedaled away from previous pronouncements in order to calm spooked bond markets—is totally meaningless.....Moreover, the recent statement of a sub-set of EU finance ministers that haircuts will be imposed on new debts issued after 2013 not the old one is actually counter-productive and ensures that PIIGS in distress will lose market access rather than regain it over time: Why would any private creditor of a PIIGS want to purchase the newly issued debt of such a sovereign when such debt—rather than the old one—would be restructured? The whole logic of DIP financing is that new debts get seniority relative to old debts—that are already locked in—to ensure that new financing arrives to a sovereign under distress. The weird EU view that new debts—rather than old ones—would be subject to debt restructuring turns the basic principle of DIP financing on its head and ensures that market access will be lost even to distressed sovereigns that still have such access.
The constraints for an orderly debt restructurings are not legal–the lack of a formal crisis resolution mechanism; they are rather political: i.e., when will the EU agree that some of its member states are not just illiquid but near insolvent and thus in need of an orderly market based restructuring of their public debts that would provide debt relief while limiting the risk of a systemic contagion to the rest of the eurozone.
Tuesday, 2 November 2010
Larry Kotlikoff on Limited Purpose Banking
An open letter from Laurence Kotlikoff of Boston University to Lord Turner, chairman of Britain’s Financial Services Authority
Dear Adair,
I listened to your terrific talk at the Soros conference. I could focus on the eloquence, fantastic delivery and numerous deep insights, but let me make a couple of comments that may be of actual value at the margin. Take them from where they emanate – real friendship and respect.
It seems that you are questioning yourself. On the one hand, you are saying it’s critical to consider radical solutions. On the other hand, you are saying, “Too radical, too fast, is too dangerous. If we move to real safely, we may need to take decades.”
And you seem to be saying, “If we get the regulators to do their jobs, we can fix this thing.” But, you’re also saying, “Regulators just failed us miserably and are working for their next bosses on Wall and Lombard streets.”
I take your public self-questioning to be an extremely healthy sign. No one can honestly contemplate the continuation of the current financial system without having deep and terrifying concerns. Yet, it also seems scary to imagine moving to a very different type of system, which has never been test-driven.
But the British public should be extremely thankful for your candour. I can’t imagine a head of the SEC providing such an open and honest appraisal of our financial ship of state, let alone admitting his uncertainty (which we all share) about knowing precisely how to fix it.
What I didn’t hear in your talk was an emphasis on the snake oil. To me, it’s the single most important factor in what happened, and the full and immediate disclosure and FDA-type verification of the securities being marketed is the only way to prevent it. It’s not prop trading, but prop information that’s the problem because the prop information is a front to sell the snake oil.
You referenced Limited Purpose Banking twice in your talk. It seemed like you got close to saying it was the way to go, at least over time, but then you said you were worried about sudden swings in the willingness of the public to extend credit to itself without traditional bankers “managing” their risks.
Let me respond.
Limited Purpose Banking (discussed in Jimmy Stewart Is Dead) has two legs – one is strict mutual fund intermediation and the other is the Federal Financial Authority that represents an FDA for the securities industry insofar as it would verify, fully and immediately disclose, and independently appraise and rate all securities bought, sold, or held by the mutual funds. When I reference disclosure, I mean, for example, displaying, in real time, on the web all of the details about each of the individual mortgages in a collateralised mortgate obligation. And yes, this would eliminate prop info about investment strategies. I think that’s a price worth paying.
Re the mutual fund leg, your talk suggested that Limited Purpose Banking might be subject to major credit swings because of changes in market perceptions. I differ for several reasons.
First, when there is disclosure, the potential for major and sudden swings in perceptions is greatly reduced. Recall the Tylenol scare back in 1984. A couple of bottles of cyanide-tainted Tylenol led, overnight, to no market for 30m bottles worldwide. The perception flipped from the pills being safe to being toxic. Once the contents of the bottles were replaced with new Tylenol and were disclosed, via safely sealed containers, to be Tylenol, as opposed to rat poison, the potential for such wild swings in the market value of Tylenol ended. I think the FFA’s disclosure, verification, rating, and appraisals will keep wild swings, which we now see, in the perception of the credit-worthiness of borrowers from occurring.
Second, you seem to be suggesting that if perceptions changed, there would be massive and sudden sale of mortgages and other loans under LPB. But the mutual funds intermediating mortgage and commercial lending would be closed-end, so there would be no fire sale of the loans themselves.
Third, you seem to be saying that the bankers are more level-headed than the public, so the public will panic, while the bankers won’t. I think the public panics when they suddenly suspect the bankers are stealing their money. Moreover, in the current setting, we have bankers fully panicked with respect to lending. Why else would they sit on more than $1 trillion in excess reserves here in the US? (Yes, the Fed is paying interest on those reserves. But what it’s paying is paltry.) I don’t see any evidence that bankers kept their cool in this crisis and kept lending. Absent Uncle Sam’s take over of Fannie and Freddie, we’d have had very few mortgages issued in the past 18 months here in the States.
Fourth, under LPB, the government is always free to intervene directly in mortgage or commercial paper mutual funds and ensure the supply of credit.
Fifth, if you are pushing for very high capital requirements (as you seem, at a minimum, to be doing), you are, in effect, pushing for each bank to become one very big mutual fund. But one big mutual fund is much less efficient than one, potentially, very big mutual fund company that markets many different mutual funds. It allows the public to buy the individual securities they want to hold.
Sixth, one can’t be a little bit pregnant. Even permitting small degrees of risk-taking by the intermediary will leave the intermediary enough rope to hang itself as well as the economy. Citigroup could have a 99 per cent capital requirement. But what if it has one trader who buys one security that has one obscure clause that commits it to a $1 trillion payout in some extreme state of nature? Well, that security may be viewed by regulators as acceptable for Citigroup to hold, but it’s not acceptable for the public who will get hit with the bill and the economic fallout. With a $600 trillion gross derivates market, losses of this magnitude aren’t out of the question.
What we need is 100 per cent capital requirements in all potential states of nature, not just the current state of nature.
All best and let’s keep debating how to move forward.
Larry
Laurence Kotlikoff is a professor of economics at Boston University and the author of Jimmy Stewart is Dead: Ending the World’s Ongoing Financial Plague with Limited Purpose Banking.
Monday, 1 November 2010
Mervyn King on Radical Bank Reform
One simple solution, advocated by my colleague David Miles, would be to move to very much higher levels of capital requirements - several orders of magnitude higher. A related proposal is to ensure there are large amounts of contingent capital in a bank's liability structure....But unless complete, capital requirements will never be able to guarantee that costs will not spill over elsewhere. This leads to the limiting case of proposals such as Professor Kotlikoff's idea to introduce what he calls "limited purpose banking". That would ensure that each pool of investments made by a bank is turned into a mutual fund with no maturity mismatch. There is no probability of alchemy. IT IS AN IDEA WORTHY OF FURTHER STUDY.
Another avenue of reform is some form of functional separation. The Volcker Rule is one example. Another,more fundamental, example would be to divorce the payment system from risky lending activity - that is, to prevent fractional reserve banking....Eliminating fractional reserve banking explicitly recognisees that the pretence that risk-free deposits can be supported by risky assets is alchemy......
The advantage of these types of more fundamental proposals is that no tax or capital requirement needs to be calibrated......But a key challenge is to ensure that maturity transformation does not simply migrate outside of the regulated perimeter, and end up benefiting from an implicit public subsidy. That is difficult because it is the nature of the services, not the institutions, that is the concern.....
The broad answer to the problem is likely to be remarkably simple. Banks should be financed much more heavily by equity rather than short-term debt.....
Of all the many ways of organising banking, the worst is the one we have today.
Mervyn King on Basel III
First, even the new levels of capital are insufficient to prevent another crisis. Calibrating required capital by reference to the losses incurred during the recent crisis takes inadequate account of the benefits to banks of massive government intervention and the implicit guarantee. More fundamentally, it fails to recognise that when sentiment changes only very high levels of capital would be sufficient to enable banks to obtain funding on anything like normal spreads to policy rates, as we can see at present. When investors change their view about the unknowable future, as they occasionally will in sudden and discontinuous ways - banks that were perceived as well-capitalised can seem under-capitalised with concerns over their solvency.....
Second, the Basel approach calculates the amount of capital required by using a measure of "risk-weighted" assets. Those risk weights are computed from past experience. Yet the circumstances in which capital needs to be available to absorb potential losses are precisely those when earlier judgements about the risk of different assets and their correlations are shown to be wrong. And that is not because investors, banks or regulators are incompetent. It is because the relevant risks are often impossible to assess in terms of fixed probabilities........That is why the Bank of England advocated a simple leverage ratio as a key backstop to capital requirements.....
Third, the Basel framework still focuses largely on the assets side of the bank's balance sheet. Basel II excluded consideration of the liquidity and liability structure of the balance sheet, so much so that when the UK adopted Basel II in 2007, of all the major banks the one with the highest capital ratio was, believe it or not, Northern Rock. Within weeks of announcing that it intended to return excess capital to its shareholders, Northern Rock ran out of money. Basel II was based on a judgement that mortgages were the safest form of lending irrespective of how they were financed. If a business model is based around a particular funding model that suddenly becomes unviable, then the business model becomes unviable too, as events in 2007 showed.
Friday, 17 September 2010
Gary Wills on B16 and Newman in the NYRB blog
Saturday, 11 September 2010
Friday, 23 July 2010
Quis custodiet ipsos custodes?
Saturday, 17 July 2010
Information from the North Concerning Ice
Friday, 16 July 2010
"JakeN" commenting on The Economist's analysis of Goldman versus the SEC
Friday, 9 July 2010
From The Economist
Monday, 5 July 2010
It's the little things
"In your interview with Monty Python actor Terry Jones ("A Python's Progress", OT, 22.2), you referred repeatedly to his involvement with the "Oxford Review". When I was at Oxford, my involvement was with the Oxford Revue. Call me picky, but I think that I was involved with the one better spelt.
Rowan Atkinson.
Queen's 1975.
Friday, 2 July 2010
Thoughts on listening to the Today programme
Tuesday, 29 June 2010
David Shulman on Gaza
“Can we make any sense of Israel’s policy toward Gaza? I think we can—a rather sinister sense—but only if we look beyond the mass of sometimes conflicting details that have emerged since the attack on the “Gaza Freedom Flotilla” on May 31. On the face of it, it’s hard to understand how any government could have decided to do anything so obviously self-defeating. At the very least Israel has handed Hamas a major propaganda victory, one that should easily have been foreseen. On the other hand, there is surely something about the whole foolish, deadly episode that is emblematic of Israeli’s current approach. Listen, first, to the public statements.
““Everything would have worked fine, but the passengers reacted inappropriately.” Thus, a headline describing the reaction of the captain who led the Israeli naval commando team onto the Mavi Marmara—the Turkish ship that was attempting to bring humanitarian aid to Gaza as part of the flotilla—and who was wounded in the ensuing struggle. (He was said to be speaking from his hospital bed.) He is certainly not alone in taking this view of the incident. In his first public statement after the debacle, Defense Minister Ehud Barak also blamed the activists on board the Turkish ship for what happened; he later added, in a striking non sequitur, that in the Middle East you cannot afford to show weakness, though that is precisely what the Israeli attack had demonstrated. Spokesmen for both the army and the government repeatedly said that the soldiers were in danger of being lynched—as if they were innocent victims of an ambush rather than, in effect, state-sponsored pirates attacking a convoy carrying humanitarian aid in international waters. The Israeli genius for “designer victimhood,” to borrow a phrase from the Indian political philosopher Jyotirmaya Sharma, is capable of surprising flashes of ingenuity.”
Monday, 7 June 2010
Matthew D'Ancona on Initiativitis
One could see the former home secretary’s nerve-endings twitching with the old instinct to open an inquiry, launch an initiative, assemble a taskforce, appoint a firearms “tsar”. It is to the Coalition’s credit that it has thus far resisted this temptation, often clumsily but accurately described as “initiativitis”. When the nation’s attention is gripped by a tragedy of this scale and horror, the pressure upon a prime minister to make promises, no matter how vapid, and take action, no matter how rushed, is immense. But David Cameron showed courage and maturity in declaring that there wasn’t always “an instant legislative or regulatory answer”.